by Darren Williams, AllianceBernstein
The COVID-19 pandemic has caused enormous dislocations in the world economy in a shockingly short time. The wave of policy support unleashed in response has stabilized activity, but it has also inflated an already sizable debt overhang. Governments now face difficult choices on how to address it.
Public-sector debt in developed economies was already at record highs before the pandemic (Display). The massive amounts of fiscal spending weâve seen to date (with more likely) could boost it by as much as 20% or more of gross domestic product (GDP) in many countries.
Some argue that mounting government debt is simply a natural by-product of secular stagnation. In this view, if the private sector isnât spending enoughâa situation COVID-9 will likely exacerbateâthe government must spend in order to avoid a depression. Others, more aligned with our view, think the debt-driven economic model of the last few decades has run out of steam, and that the world is stuck in a debt trap.
The End Game: Evaluating Historical Debt-Reduction Templates
If extreme government debt levels arenât desirableâand history comes down strongly in favor of this perspectiveâgovernments need to do something about it.
To help us dimension the different paths developed economies might follow, we can lay out four historical templates: the UK experience after the Napoleonic Wars; Germanyâs Weimar Republic after World War I; the path followed by the US, the UK and other western economies after World War II; and Japan post-1990.
Thereâs very little appetite for a long period of fiscal adjustment right now, so itâs safe to rule out the belt tightening used to reduce debt from eye-watering levels in nineteenth-century Britain. The path Germany chose to follow in the years after World War I led to a period of vicious hyperinflationâa stark warning of the risks that can emerge when a country monetizes debt by having the central bank finance government spending. This scenario could emerge again if an extreme version of modern monetary theory were rolled out and misused, but we doubt that any country will follow that path in the near future.
Narrowing the Choices: Post-WWII Formula or Japan Post-1990s?
This leaves us with two debt-reduction paths. One is the postâWorld War II formula of strong economic growth, inflation and financial repression (ultralow interest rates).
Because strong growth isnât on the menu today, the path really comes down to a mixture of financial repression and higher inflation. The second path leads to Japanâs post-1990 experience: weak growth, unfavorable demographics, rising debt, ultralow rates andâultimatelyâdeflation.
Trying to gauge which route the world will follow is probably the biggest controversy facing financial markets today. We favor some version of the postâWorld War II period and higher inflation over the template from post-1990 Japan and deflation. Not only is Japan an outlier in economic history, but rising populism and deglobalization also point toward the first path.
The Missing Puzzle Piece
Moreover, weâre starting to see concrete signs of the regime shift needed to underpin higher inflationâthe Fedâs recent shift toward average inflation targeting is another important step in this direction.
But weâre not there yet. The final piece of the puzzle is a credible commitment to drive inflation expectations higher. This may involve the abandonment of the inflation targeting regime, which, helped by demographics and globalization, has underpinned the low-inflation era of the last three or four decades.
Darren Williams is DirectorâGlobal Economic Research at AllianceBernstein (AB). Guy Bruten is Chief EconomistâAsia-Pacific ex China at AB.
The views expressed herein do not constitute research, investment advice or trade recommendations and do not necessarily represent the views of all AB portfolio-management teams. Views are subject to change over time.
This post was first published at the official blog of AllianceBernstein..