by Ben Masters, Third Wave Finance, via Clarity Financial
One of the common side effects of debt-fueled speculation/spending isĀ financialization, and one should immediately look to the growth and prominence of the financial industry (since the 1980s) with alarm, hesitation and concern; how and why is it that an industry that produces no physical product has grown to its current size? Ā After all, the financial industry exists as a non-production-utility ā its very purpose is to properly allocate capital and resources to desirable (in-demand) industries;Ā itās an industry whose very existence relies on the success of other industries. If the financial industry is able to properly allocate capital/resources to desirable industries, itās rewarded and is able to grow along with those other fundamental industries; and if a misallocation occurs, capital/resources are allocated to (and used up by) unsuccessful industries ā those industries then shrink, along with the finance industry and economic growth.
The concern then is that if a general āhollowing outā of production occurs in a country ā something that is rarely disputed these days when addressing U.S. industry ā this would typically result in a smaller financial industry, not a larger one; yet the explosion of growth in the finance industry since the 1980s has been in stark contrast.Ā Why is this? Ā Put simply, debt-fueled investment speculation and debt-based spending has exploded since the 1980s.
Debt-fueled investment speculation can be seen in this visual of the threeĀ instances of the 21st century where long-term returns for stocks have been reduced ā each peak fueled by different forms of speculation that ensure low future returns:
Tradable securities far outpacing economic growthā¦
The three speculative episodes of the 21st century, and dangerous transition periodsā¦
Each of these speculative episodes have been addressed inĀ The Orchestration of Debt-Based Expansions; and the topic of debt-based spending (pursued since the 1980s) has been written about as well, and includes government debt and consumer debt (mortgages, credit cards, student loans, car loans, borrowing to supplement falling incomes, etc.): see Debt Levels,Ā Why does college cost so much?,Ā Why doesnāt anyone earn anything in a bank account anymore?, and Income Stagnation.
The dilemma is that debtĀ temporarily inflates the price of desirable assets (until the point in time where that debt needs to be paid back), and if a majority of the economy has debt that needs to be paid back economic growth is constrained ā at some point in time those individuals are paying back loans instead of boosting economic growth through spending. Ā And if the majority of the economy has unproductive debt (debt that has not created an income stream to repay the principal amount borrowed and interest on the debt) then defaults, write-downs, etc. have a punishing affect on the economy and financial system.
For many, that punishing affect is a destruction of investments (which are not the same as wealth⦠see Fundamental Wealth). Ā Their āassetsā evaporate, prices plunge,Ā and they donāt know why⦠ The reason that assets vanishĀ in a market crisis is becauseĀ debt is always considered an asset by the issuer, yet in reality debt isnāt always an asset for the issuer; there are improper claims of assets ā assets that donāt exist (loans that wonāt be able to be paid back). Ā In effect, there are claims of assets (and securities issued onĀ those āassetsā) thatĀ outnumber the actual underlying assets.
Itās the financialization due to debt/leverage/speculation ā the adding of layers and complexities ā that can lead to a weakening of the market structure; one need only look to Charles Kindlebergerās work Manias, Panics, and Crashes to see how this process has unfolded over and over throughout history.
āSpeculative manias gather speed through expansion of money and credit. . .there are many more economic expansions than there are manias.Ā But every mania has been associated with the expansion of credit.Ā In the last hundred or so years the expansion of credit has been almost exclusively through the banks and the financial system.
In boom, entropy in regulation and supervision builds up danger spots that burst into view when the boom levels off.āĀ ā Charles Kindleberger
And soĀ financialization ā the prominence of the finance industry and the growing dominance of obscure types of investments (many of which are simply more expensive packages of existing investments) ā is made plain and clear: since the 1980s, it has grownĀ due toĀ temporary debt-based investment speculation and debt-based spending. Ā And although financialization is temporary (debt constraints eventually cause a readjustment), the real danger is that the temporary misallocation-of-wealth that occursĀ rewards the financial industryĀ in a boom/bust cycle; wealth and capital that would have been used in other in-demandĀ industries (had productive debt been pursued)Ā is instead concentrated and used up in the financial industry, and when coupled with the ability to influence politics this temporary reward/misallocation can cause a further entrenchment of the undeservedly rewarded industry ā a further misallocation of wealth.
Said in 2009 by Jeremy Grantham, co-founder and chief investment strategist of Grantham, Mayo, & Van Otterloo ā one of the largest investment companies in the worldā¦
āIād like to challenge the usefulness ā not just of new instruments ā but of large tracts of the whole financial industry, much of which is a net drag. Ā Letās start with the investment management business, because I think intuitively, obviously, you can see that we collectively add nothing. Ā We produce no āwidgetsā, we shuffle the existing value of all corporations and bonds around, in a cosmic poker game. Ā At the end of each year, the investment community is down by one percent (cough)ā¦the individual is down by two, and aggregate fees have steadily grown. Ā As we grew by ten times from ā89 to ā99 huge economies of scale were existing, but the fees-per-dollar-managed grows ā no fee competition at all, contrary to theory. Ā Why? Ā Agency problems, asymmetry of information, the client canāt tell talent from luck or risk taking, and as we add new products (options, futures, CDOs, hedge funds, private equity) aggregate fees rise as a percentage of assets; there becomes a layer of fees and another layer of agents and fees ā the more complicated and opaque, the more the client need us. . .
As fees go up by half-a-percent, we reach into the clientās balance sheet, snatch the half-a-percent, and turn it into income; itās almost magic ā capital into income⦠but we lower the savings rate of our clients (savings and investment rate) by half-a-percent as our fees go up, so we get short term GDP kick from our income, at the expense of lower long-term growth on the part of the system. Ā Similarly with the whole financial system⦠let us say by 1965 (the best decade we ever had, the ā60s)Ā there was a very financial financial-service arrangement ā enough banking, enough letters of credit, to get the job done. Ā
Adequate tools are vital ā thatās not the issue.Ā Weāre talking the razzmatazz of the last ten or fifteen years⦠ The financial system was 3%Ā of GDP in 1965 ā itās now 7 1/2; this is an extra 4% load that the real economy carries. Ā The financial system overfeeds and slows down the real economy. Ā The first hundred years, up to 1965, the economy was like a battleship, growing at 3.5% a year. Ā Even the great depression bounced off it. Ā After 1965 the GDP (ex-financials) grew at 3.2; after 1982, at 3.1; after 2000, at 2.3; all of these to the end of ā07 (not including the current problems). Ā From societyās point of view this 4% works like looting, or an earthquake ā both increase GDP short term, but chew up capital. Ā They might as well be retirees or children ā all these extra people in the financial businessā but they are much, much more, expensive. Ā
Economists have not studied the optimal size for finance ā indeed, a learned journal recently rejected a paper on the grounds that finance does not comment on social utility; that is perhaps why the risks are little. Ā
The underlying problem recently has been touching faith in capitalism, this faith was based on 50 years of a dominant economic theory that was shockingly not based on facts but on unestablished, unprovable, assumptions: ārational expectationsā ā this has given us efficient markets.Ā So why regulate new instruments, if capitalism and markets are efficient? Ā Or why regulate anything? Ā So Greenspan, Rubens, Summers, and the SEC, happily beat back Brooksley Borne trying to regulate new instruments. But as Keynes knew in 1934, markets are behavioral jungles, racked by changing animal spirits, and by agency problems. Ā Efficient markets assume symmetry of data on all sides. Ā In real life, agents have all the data and the principal clients know little.Ā Itās like taking candy from babies, the more opaque and complicated the new instruments, the easier the ripoff. Ā There is now ā at LSE [London School of Economics] ā a Centre for the Study of Capital Market Dysfunctionality, started by my former colleague, Paul Woolley, that is even now, attempting an academese, to establish that in the real world condition, agents in finance tend towards getting everything.āĀ ā Jeremy Grantham, 5:33 mark ofĀ 2009 Buttonwood Gathering

Benjamin Masters a guest contributor to www.RealInvestmentAdvice.com, is the creator, designer, and writer for Third Wave Finance; he has relied on over ten years of financial services industry experience (working as a lead Portfolio Analyst) to develop this educational resource. You can contact Ben via Twitter, Linked-in, or Facebook.