The H-Curve
by Guy Haselmann, Director, Capital Markets Strategy, Scotiabank GBM
ā¢ Letās picture a graph where the x variable is a central bankās official interest rate and the y variable is the resulting economic benefit.
ā¢ Economic benefits of central bank accommodation are non-linear. Non-linear functions have slopes that change. In fact, the āeconomic benefitsā slope will differ at every point along the curve. This is somewhat obvious as a slope measures the rate of change and central bankers admit that their effectiveness weakens over time and with each successive ease.
ā¢ This point is true, yet incomplete. It suggests that marginally declining utility will eventually cause the slope to drop zero; i.e., at some point further accommodation will simply provide no economic benefit. However, the truth is that central bank stimulus is a parabolic function, whereby the slope goes negative at a certain point. The peak point at which the slope begins to change direction is the parabolaās vertex, or the point at which the level of central bank accommodation is optimal.
ā¢ Central banks seem to be operating by a different function. Their rhetoric and ideology suggests belief in a perpetually positively sloped line, whose worst case slope is simply one that is less positive over time. In other words, the second derivative or rate of change in the slope is the only thing that falls; that is, until a zero slope is reached. In truth, too much accommodation can cause long-run damage and risks to financial stability.
ā¢ There are indeed many moving parts that impact and change the vertex level. Different paradigms result in different optimal vertex levels. However, the exercise is still worthwhile. After all, how many times in an economics class does a professor utter the words āall else being equal?ā Certainly, a regime with tight regulatory and fiscal policies would move the vertex (the optimal level) to a more accommodative stance (lower official interest rates). The point is to find the true interest rate floor (a level that likely not 0%)
ā¢ A good analogy for the H-curve might be the Laffer Curve. This curve represents the relationship between rates of taxation and the resulting level of government revenue. The curve shows how taxable income changes in response to changes in the rate of taxation (i.e., income inelasticity). It theorizes that no income would be raised at the extreme rates of 0% and 100%.
ā¢ At the extremes, the y-axis of the Laffer Curve stops at zero (no revenue). However, on the H-curve, the y-axis outputs can fall well below zero (negative economic benefits) with the wrong amount of central bank stimulus.
ā¢ Moreover, the H-curve will be more time-varying and act different during policy reversals (exit strategies).
ā¢ Iāve argued for many years that central bank interest rates set below a certain level were counter-productive. Savers, pension funds, and insurance companies are certainly punished. It seems that zero and negative interest rates cause damage to consumer sentiment and elsewhere. (See March 4 note: āToppling Scales of Balanceā)
ā¢ Interest rates below a certain level hurt lending, because low margins disincentivize lenders who might feel margins do not adequately compensate them for the risks. In a fractional reserve banking system, bank lending is oil for the economic engine. Velocity of money has collapsed for a reason, probably other than regulation.
ā¢ Central bank policy is supposed to work on an 18-24 month lag, yet markets have come to expect action at every meeting in which growth and inflationary goals have not been met. Central banks need to change these expectations and stop promising more than they can deliver. After all, the H-curve suggests a negative impact.
ā¢ Ineffectiveness can damage central bank credibility. Can central banks really achieve their goals of the perfect amount (2%) of āgoldilocksā inflation? They can achieve hyper-inflation like Zimbabwe or Venezuela, but can they orchestrate the fine-tuned micro-managed amount of 2%; particularly in a complex globalized world?
ā¢ I am working to develop the H-curve more thoroughly. I thought the name was catchy and easier to say than the Haselmann-Curve. The graph is easy to envision. The actual equation might take some more time to develop.
ā¢ The key to the equation will be to determine the level at which the slope turns negative. The H-curve numerator formula may have to include a data-mining function that searches for use of military, or weapon, references by central bank officials. The tipping point might occur when the use of the following terms reach a certain level: bazooka; fire power; shock and awe; whatever it takes; arsenal, ammunition, war chest, arrows, preemptive strike, and bullets. The Fed is at war against economic and financial market weakness.
ā¢ In the movie āWar Gamesā, the military super-computer was programed to predict possible outcomes of nuclear war by playing tic-tac-toe against itself. In the end, it learned that not only are there no winners, but āthe only winning move is not to playā. Zero and negative rates could be their nuclear war.
āLaissez faire et laissez passer, le mode va de lui mĆŖmeā ā Jacques Claude Marie Vincent Gournay
Regards,
Guy
Guy Haselmann | Capital Markets Strategy
ā¬ā¬ā¬ā¬ā¬ā¬ā¬ā¬ā¬ā¬ā¬ā¬ā¬ā¬ā¬ā¬ā¬ā¬ā¬ā¬ā¬ā¬ā¬ā¬ā¬ā¬ā¬
Scotiabank | Global Banking and Markets
250 Vesey Street | New York, NY 10281
T-212.225.6686 | C-917-325-5816
guy.haselmann[at]scotiabank.com
Scotiabank is a business name used by The Bank of Nova Scotia