Little Things Mean a Lot
by Clifford Asness, Ph. D. AQR Capital Management, Inc.
My colleagues have produced a paper on something we call, perhaps pretentiously though we canât come up with a better word for it, âcraftsmanshipâ â what we believe to be a necessary part in creating successful factor portfolios. What factors (value, momentum, small, quality, others?) you believe in, or dismiss, gets much of the attention.
Thatâs understandable and appropriate. But we think there are many smaller decisions that each can matter some, and collectively can matter a lot. I wonât repeat the analysis and examples from the paper here (please read it!). But, I will use this essay as an excuse to discuss, in brief, two separate topics that Iâd been planning to write about for a while (I still might expound upon these more in the future).
Fees
The first one is factor investing fees. Yes, Iâm now the fox writing an essay on how much to pay the henhouse guards. Thatâs your last warning â the rest will be my honest opinion, but itâs obviously impossible for me to be completely unbiased. Of course, if âcraftsmanshipâ (again, read the paper!) ex-ante matters and if it varies across managers, then it is rational to have variation in fees across managers even if they espouse the same factors and philosophy.
Thus, you can accurately take away from the craftsmanship paper that you should rationally be willing to pay factor managers who have better craftsmanship slightly more than others. One may also take away the implicit and self-aggrandizing belief that we fall into that category.
Still, I want to make an even more obvious point about fees, one that I think surprisingly gets lost sometimes. Magnitude matters, and fees for factor based investing are, in general, already much lower than traditional active management. Basically, a move from fees like 150 basis points (e.g., traditional active management) to fees like 30 basis points (e.g., factor tilted long-only portfolios) is pretty huge.1 By contrast, a move from 30 to 20 basis points, not so much.2,3
Make no mistake, all-else-equal, lower fees are better! But the plausibility of all-else-not-being-equal gets substantially higher when the absolute differences in fees get much lower. For example, on 500 basis points of active risk the reduction in fees from 150 to 30 basis points is equivalent to a Sharpe/information ratio pickup of 0.24 (a 120 basis point reduction divided by 500).4
That may seem low to those used to the Sharpe ratios so many managers claim, but itâs a reasonably big number. Itâs a non-trivial fraction of the Sharpe ratio of the whole stock market over modern history. So, in that sense itâs a very big savings. Now, an additional fee reduction from 30 to 20 basis points is worth 0.02 Sharpe ratio âpoints.â
This 0.02 may seem trivial, but if you think thereâs any non-trivial difference in craftsmanship among implementers itâs far more plausible that itâs worth 0.02 rather than 0.24 Sharpe points. This means if you think the manager charging 30 basis points has a better than 0.02 Sharpe advantage youâd happily take them over the manager charging 20 basis points. Yes, this is all kind of obvious, and all Iâve proven here is that big numbers matter more than small numbers. But in a world where we have seen major fee reductions for some types of management over the last, say, decade, I think this perspective indeed gets lost sometimes as the numbers have indeed all gotten smaller.
The Tyranny of Small Decisions
Even if (if!) youâre making a large collection of small decisions correctly there can be long periods in which these decisions hurt instead of help you. This is true collectively, looking at the net of all these choices, and even more so when each decision is viewed standalone. Getting your time horizon lined up with some rational expectations is always a huge issue in investing. But, itâs perhaps more of an issue here as the edge to âsmall decisionsâ is almost by definition smaller. And, there are often a lot of them to make. One important subtlety is that one cannot avoid at least attempting some form of craftsmanship as choices have to be made.5
Letâs just make up an example. Imagine there are ten independent (uncorrelated) sources of âcraftsmanship alphaâ and that each adds 2 basis points of expected return at the cost of 20 basis points of tracking error from each (against some idea of a super simple ânon-craftedâ alternative.)6 Each is thus a 0.10 Sharpe ratio viewed alone. Together they are expected to add 20 basis points to the overall factor implementation inducing 63 basis points of tracking error (20 basis points times the square-root of ten). Thatâs a Sharpe ratio of 0.32 from the collective craftsmanship (in addition to the basic factor returns).
This is not a bad deal particularly, say, continuing the example posited above where this craftsmanship costs an extra 10 basis points in fees.
But, as many have noted in other contexts, a Sharpe ratio like 0.32 can be hard to live with. Its chance of subtracting from your performance in a given year is about 37%. Its chance of subtracting over five years is about 24%. And, wait for it⊠over twenty years the chance it subtracts is still about 8%. Thatâs right. Thereâs a non-trivial chance your craftsmanship is every bit as good as you think, and it subtracts over two full decades, perhaps the lionâs share of your career. Such is the unforgiving, uncaring math.7
Now, if you think those stats are bracing for the full set of ten unrelated additive pieces of craftsmanship, each with a 0.10 Sharpe ratio, then you are entering a special kind of hell if you are evaluating each on their own. Sharpe advantages of 0.10 have a 33% chance of losing over twenty-year periods. That means an individual minor improvement you believe in, and you are right about, could quite easily let you down over your career.
Of course, a remaining question is how one can ever be confident in each individual piece of craftsmanship if they are 0.10 Sharpe ratios viewed standalone. There is no magic answer (and please remember that you do have to choose!), and it is similar to getting comfortable with any strategy. We consider basic economic sense (âdiversify across equally intuitive ways to measure a factorâ, âdonât take unintended risksâ, âtrade as cheaply as you canâ), and we look at evidence from very long periods, importantly and hopefully obtained in many places (geographies and assets classes).
Despite them all being small advantages when viewed alone, we are confident enough, for instance, in the examples highlighted in the craftsmanship paper to make these many small decisions and to believe our strategies may be enhanced (slightly) long-term as a result of them. But we also know that even assuming weâre right we might have some explaining to do for long periods. This is the business we have chosen.8
Back to the Craftsmanship Paper
Whether or not you believe in factor investing, what factors you believe in, and how much you believe in each (for weighting your bets), are all first order in the factor investing world. But the things we call craftsmanship, detailed in this paper full of examples, matter too. They can matter at least as much as modest fee differentials â that is, Little Things Mean a Lot â«. But, as with the factors themselves, they need to be based on economic common sense and as much in- and out-of-sample evidence as possible. This is true for most things in investing but perhaps even more so when the edges are smaller.
*****
Footnotes:
[1] This very ballpark example is meant to be about traditional active management versus todayâs factor tilted long-only portfolios. If we were talking about alternative investments the example might be the old â2&20â for hedge funds against something more like â1â today for long-short multi-factor portfolios. Another issue in fee analysis is comparing fees on properly constructed market-neutral alternatives, particularly ones run at reasonably aggressive levels of expected return / risk, to those on traditional long-only tilted portfolios (which are best viewed as a blend of passive index exposures and small factor tilts). The fees per unit of factor exposure should be in the ballpark of each other. Meaning, the fee should be lower in many traditional long-only implementations as you are getting more benchmark exposure (which should cost less than factor exposure) and less factor exposure versus less traditional long-short implementations. But, backing out some idea of the fees per unit of factor exposure should reveal a closer correspondence in fees even between seemingly very different investment products. This is another topic I canât do justice to here but hope to return to at some point. [2] Absolute, not relative, moves are what matter here. In other words, what matters is the reduction from 30 to 20 basis points saves the investor 10 basis points, not that it reduces the fees by 33.33%. Percentages get kind of silly the closer you are to starting at zero. [3] My favorite example is some recent advertisements for index funds where one company shows their fees vs. anotherâs and the upshot is âthey are at 5.5 basis points but weâre at 4.5!â OK, yes, if literally everything else is equal take the 4.5. Alternatively, if you think, based on analysis, intuition, or indigestion, that the 5.5 basis point manager might have the tiniest edge then you may want to choose them instead. Either way please keep in mind that we are talking about a 1 basis point difference on a 15-20% volatility asset so it really doesnât matter a hill of beans to ending wealth. We are all trained that small differences in long-term compound returns matter more than people generally think to ending wealth. Thatâs generally true. But, not for 1 basis point differences⊠[4] âSharpe ratioâ is usually used for absolute return while âinformation ratioâ used for return relative to a benchmark. Iâm just going to say Sharpe from now on here and trust it to make sense in context. [5] Choices have to be made with traditional indexing also, but with factors we donât get to start with anything quite as ex-ante reasonable as market-cap weighting. For instance, while I worship at the altar of Fama and French, I donât think decisions like going long the lowest price-to-book third of the market and short the highest price-to-book third, separately among large and small caps, all cap weighted, has quite the same claim to ex-ante reasonableness relative to other possible alternatives to implementing a portfolio as the more Bogle-esque âgo long everything at market cap weights.â [6] Admittedly without an agreed upon standard way of implementing factors I do face a bit of a âcompared to whatâ problem. But, I think the basic idea that there are lots of decisions that can potentially add (or subtract) small value is well represented by this example. [7] To be clear, the probability math in this example applies irrespective of the source of the gain â whether the said 0.32 Sharpe ratio is earned through the equity premium, through a good factor choice, or through many small craftsmanship decisions. The broader point is that many ex-ante advantages may disappoint at surprisingly long evaluation periods. It is all too common for investors, ourselves sometimes included, to implicitly expect any ex-ante edge to be realized consistently at shorter horizons than simple probability calculations indicate. [8] If you combine many small craftsmanship decisions, each possessing a very small edge, with a modern quantâs ability and predilection to measure all of their individual ex-post contributions, itâs a recipe for certain âpersonality typesâ to always be in a bad mood. Iâm not saying who.This post was originally published at AQR Capital
Copyright © AQR Capital