Modern Monetary Theory is the winner…at least for now

by Martin Sibileau, A View from the Trenches

“…MMT is to me the 21st century re-incarnation, in monetary policy, of
Cardinal Richelieu’s raison d’état concept. If I am correct, it will bring
the same serious consequences it brought in the 17th century…”

 (To read this article in pdf format, click here: April 14 2013)

If I have to summarily describe the events of the past week, I will say that it was the week Modern Monetary Theory won over any other school of thought…(I promise you this: Today’s letter will not be a rant…)

Brief introduction to Modern Monetary Theory

I suggest you do your own research on this topic, because what I will say here is by no means exhaustive. But it is important to be aware of a new reality. I, for one, found a fair summary of it here. Below is a list of some theses held by this school, from L. Randall Wray’s Modern Monetary Theory: A Primer on Macroeconomics for Sovereign Monetary Systems”(From chapter 18, edited by me):

“Statements that do NOT apply to a currency-issuer:

-Governments have a budget constraint (like households and firms) and have to raise funds through taxing or borrowing

-Government deficits drive interest rates up, crowd out the private sector…and necessarily lead to inflation

-Government deficits leave debt for future generations: government needs to cut spending or tax more today to diminish this burden

-Government deficits take away savings that could be used for investment

-We need savings to finance investment and the government’s deficit

While these statements are consistent with the conventional wisdom, and while they are more-or-less accurate if applied to the case of a government that does not issue its own currency, they do not apply to a currency issuer…”

“…Principles that DO apply to a currency issuer. Let us replace these false statements with propositions that are true of any currency issuing government, even one that operates with a fixed exchange rate regime:

-The government names a unit of account and issues a currency denominated in that unit;

-The government ensures a demand for its currency by imposing a tax liability that can be fulfilled by payment of its currency;

-Government spends by crediting bank reserves and taxes by debiting bank reserves; in this manner, banks act as intermediaries between government and the non government sector, crediting depositor’s accounts as government spends and debiting them when taxes are paid;

-Government deficits mean net credits to banking system reserves and also to non government deposits at banks;

-Central banks set the overnight interest rate target; it adds/drains reserves as needed to hit its target rate;

-The overnight interest rate target is “exogenous”, set by the central bank; the quantity of reserves is “endogenous” determined by the needs and desires of private banks; and the “deposit multiplier” is simply an ex post ratio of reserves to deposits—it is best to think of deposits as expanding endogenously as they “leverage” reserves, but with no predetermined leverage ratio;

-The treasury cooperates with the central bank, providing new bond issues to drain excess reserves, or retiring bonds when banks are short of reserves; for this reason, bond sales are not a borrowing operation used by the sovereign government, instead they are a “reserve maintenance” tool that helps the central bank to hit interest rate targets;

-The treasury can always “afford” anything for sale in its own currency, although government always imposes constraints on its spending; and lending by the central bank is not constrained except through constraints imposed by government (including operational constraints adopted by the central bank itself).

I could discuss at length (and likely shall have to in the future) how I disagree with the statements above, but today it is not relevant. Today, that school of thought won the day and rather than criticism, I believe it merits that we acknowledge its existence and understand its implications.

Historical context of Modern Monetary Theory (MMT)

MMT is to me the 21st century re-incarnation, in monetary policy, of Cardinal Richelieu’s raison d’état concept. If I am correct, it will bring the same serious consequences it brought in the 17th century (In his book “Diplomacy”, Henry Kissinger gives Cardinal Richelieu all the credit for this political concept. It is very unfair. About a century earlier, Niccolò Machiavelli dedicated his book “The Prince” precisely to encourage the Medici family to undertake his dream of national unification in Italy. Yet, Kissinger did not devote one single sentence of his book to Machiavelli).

When Cardinal Richelieu thought of état, he thought along the terms most of us can relate to. When Modern Monetary Theory discusses sovereignty, the borders change: We can no longer speak of states, but of fiat currency jurisdictions; and there are only two: The one corresponding to the global reserve fiat currency and the one corresponding to the rest of fiat currencies, which are benchmarked to the global reserve.

Why Modern Monetary Theory won last week

Perhaps to MMT, its raison d’état is its very same existence. When Richelieu (but not Machiavelli) thought about état, he did not think in état as “the” entity in itself. He thought of France, as a particular case. MMT however is universal; its raison d’etat is the survival of fiat currencies, which forces policy makers to cooperate globally in order to destroy any other alternative currencies. In the case of gold, precisely, I methodically proved it in an earlier letter (here).

On April 4th, we had a strong indication that the raison d’etat was becoming increasingly relevant. During a press conference, Mr. Draghi, answering a question from Zerohedge.com, stated that “… people(…)  vastly underestimate what the Euro means for the Europeans (…); they vastly underestimate the amount of political capital that has been invested in the Euro...”  I thought he was very wrong. I don’t think anyone actually underestimates them, which is why I so fear that this game will end in a war, as unseen unemployment rates are coerced upon millions of innocent families.

Then, last week we saw the evidence of MMT realpolitik at work: First with Bitcoins and then with gold. Both destroyed on no fundamentals. In the case of gold, it even occurred at precisely predicted timing. Because even if Draghi openly did (although in a more subtle way) what Gordon Brown did in May of 1999, the prospect of Cyprus selling its gold had already been made public two days before last Friday (April 12th). Therefore, this was not a new fundamental. Hence, having not been enough, the typical take down on gold first at 4:00am ET, then at 8:20am and 10:30am ensued (see chart below).

 

Free, open, markets cannot be anticipated in such way. Yet I can remember pointing out to you the precise timing of these moves in earlier letters (i.e.”… I am tired of seeing endless proof of suppression (i.e. the typical take downs in the price at either 8:20am ET or at 10am-11am ET, with impressive predictability) …February 21, 2013”). Nothing else to add here. If a schmuck like me can tell you months in advance that a market price will fall at 8:20am and 10am and you see that price falling at 8:20am and 10am, then….

Why did bitcoin and gold collapse? (And make no mistake, because gold did collapse). Because they are not redeemable. In the first case,  it is easier to accept this. In the second, most will disagree with me. To those, I answer that as long as the US government can refuse (or get away with refusing) to deliver the physical gold to a central bank the sorts of the Bundesbank, one can safely say that regardless of the marginal bullion held by retail in safety boxes or bullion banks in vaults, for all practical purposes, gold shall be negated. I am deeply disappointed with myself, for not having understood this fact earlier, of course.

There are those who still think China will reveal its true holdings of gold. Personally, I think it is very unlikely. They would be acting against their own interest.

What next? Upcoming challenges to Modern Monetary Theory

As at April 2013, I can see three main challenges to MMT. If they are overcome by MMT, freedom as we know it, will be a thing of the past.  They can be temporarily overcome, with coercion,  and the words of Mr. Draghi at his last press conference are more than ominous in this regard. Times like these have taken place in every century of the history of civilization, and I see no reason to deny the probability of them occurring once again in the 21st. In no particular order, these are the challenges:

-Annihilating the last bastion of redeemable, alternative marketable value:

After April 13th, the last bastion of redeemable and alternative market value is in agricultural commodities. Because these are perishable, they cannot be stored away and refused to deliver, like precious metals. Because they cannot be stored away, they cannot be exponentially securitized. And because they cannot be exponentially securitized, their price cannot be sustainably manipulated.

Furthermore, if redeemability was affected, these markets would segment, into one with capped prices (where nobody sells), and an underground one, where inflation expectations inevitably will be shaped. In addition, their production is not the monopoly of any particular country and the rise in its prices, always ends in social conflict (as my uncle Alberto Mario once told me: “Every revolution begins with a baker being hanged by the mob”).

This will be a challenge, although not new. In the past, it has always been addressed with price controls, from the times of the grain trade between Egypt and Rome, to the 1930s with the creation of grain/meat Boards, which were monopolies that failed miserably at containing inflation. Canada and Argentina, for instance, are an example of the latter.  I have to give the intellectual credit to Albert Friedberg, founder of the Friedberg Mercantile Group, for bringing this challenge to light and remembering the Russian wheat deal of July-August 1972 (Mr. Friedberg’s quarterly conference calls are invaluable. This topic was discussed on January 31st here, after the 38th minute)

There is no doubt in my mind that MMT will address with this challenge with repression too. In the process, food prices will rise but as I wrote before (here), this will not mean that Jim Rogers will be proved right. Farmers will not drive Lamborghinis. Prices will rise precisely because the opposite will occur and scarcity of production will be the norm.

-Overcoming the lack of a price system to allocate resources:

When prices are suppressed, markets cannot efficiently allocate resources. When this happens, defaults eventually follow. And as they take place and production falls, the difference between the former and actual output is seen as something negative. Of course, in a world with fiat currency and leverage, this gap is brutal. In a world without leverage, this would be mere evidence of creative destruction.

One of the most (if not the most) flawed concepts in non-Austrian economics is that of the existence of an output gap, which has to be closed by economic policy. The concept is so deeply embedded and so little challenged that it is assumed right away without further ado. It was in Martin Feldstein’s article (“When interest rates rise”) two weeks ago and it is in the famous Taylor’s policy rule.

The idea of an output gap denies the role played by the price system in allocating resources. In other words, it would be very wrong to think that because I could work until 10pm but leave my work regularly at 6pm, my output gap is 4 hours worth of my productivity. Why? Because I consciously decide to leave at 6pm, since I am not paid enough to stay at the office until 10pm. Vice versa, my employer does not see any marginal value that would be compelling enough to pay me for those additional hours. Therefore, even though the capacity/ infrastructure is there for me to stay at the office until 10pm, it is simply mistaken to infer that there is an output gap. It is even more idiotic to believe that by lowering interest rates, my employer would be willing to invest more, to fill that hypothetical gap.

There is one more angle to this. If there is a gap, it is understood that at some point in the past, I used to work until 10pm and now that I no longer do, it would be desirable that I go back to work until 10pm everyday. Why? Nobody wonders why I decided not to work until 10pm. Nobody asks why resources are no longer allocated to work from 6pm to 10pm. The reallocation of resources (of my time) is completely ignored. In the same fashion, when governments seek to close that gap manipulating the inter-temporal rate of exchange (i.e. interest rates), rather than facilitate a natural reallocation of resources, they insist with sustaining the old state of affairs, which was not desired, in the first place.

The idea of an output gap is Aristotelian in nature, and had Galileo been an economist in 2013, he would have invited Mr. Feldstein, Krugman or Bernanke to see for themselves that there has never been high inflation with full employment of resources; that high inflation is never triggered by an increase in demand, but by a lack of supply, when production collapses destroyed by fiscal and financial repression.  The scene of high inflation is a scene of empty shelves at supermarkets while goods are transacted at higher prices in underground markets; enforced high minimum wages under which nobody gets employed; banks that post negative lending interest rates but lend to no one (except their governments); entrepreneurs who borrow outside the system or vendor financing replacing working capital lines from banks.

With the steadily increasing level of financial repression, how will this challenge present itself to MMT? Via defaults. Until last week, I was convinced that these defaults would come first from the European Union. Now, I am inclined to accept the possibility that they originate in Japan. How will MMT deal with them? By creating more liquidity, of course. By further suppressing any possible signal.

-Suppressing a spiraling of inflation expectations in Japan:

The recent change in regime at the Bank of Japan merits a lot more than this final comment. When I have a moment, I will address it. Meanwhile, it is becoming clear to me that Japan is close to entering a Latin American-style spiraling cycle, where inflation expectations take the lead and the central bank can only follow.

As the Yen is devalued, capital in Yen-denominated fixed income and credit flees and is reallocated in the same, but USD denominated, asset classes. This simple movement increases interest rates in Yen, which is counterproductive to the initial efforts by the Bank of Japan. The Bank has to therefore purchase even more Yen-denominated debt, which triggers a further devaluation. As the devaluation makes imported commodities/food more expensive, the rate of devaluation channeled through to consumer prices can shape inflation expectations and the market may incorporate the expected rate of devaluation to Yen nominal yields.

Indexation is MMT’s worst nightmare. They were able to postpone it destroying the gold market, but this may prove a more formidable challenge. The unintended consequence of the Yen intervention is that the Bank of Japan ends up indirectly effecting quantitative easing on USD debt; both sovereign and private. This was in my view another bearish driver for gold, as the need for direct Fed intervention in the US Treasury market, on the margin, decreases.

As capital out of Japan floods the USD corporate debt market, credit spreads compress even further, weakening correlations among asset classes and making eventual defaults, of global consequence, more likely and dangerous. In summary, MMT is faced here with perhaps its biggest challenge, because the spiraling process just described sets the stage for an uncooperative Japanese central bank, which will be terribly busy trying to fix the unfixable. In Latin America, MMT often crystallizes in a controlled and segmented foreign exchange market. But this is unconceivable in a G-7 country like Japan and if any hint of it was even suggested, chaos of an unseen scale would fall upon the Asia Pacific region, dragging the rest of the world with it.

Conclusion

Last week, without any doubt, Modern Monetary Theory had a great victory. We are not in Kansas any more. From now on, without any price signals left, we will only be guided by volume, particularly in the labour market. This situation will persist until finally a new signal emerges. Whether it will come from the agricultural commodity market, the European Union or the Japanese fixed income market, remains to be seen.

Martin Sibileau

Total
0
Shares
Previous Article

“Fortune’s Formula” (Saut)

Next Article

7 Answers to the Critical Questions on Investors’ Minds (Koesterich)

Related Posts
Subscribe to AdvisorAnalyst.com notifications
Watch. Listen. Read. Raise your average.