Why We Don't Rebalance (Hsu)

 
by Jason Hsu, Research Affiliates LLC

For investors, the $1 million question is, “Why don’t all of us rebalance?” Research shows compellingly the long-term benefit of rebalancing, yet anecdotal evidence suggests that most investors do not rebalance their portfolios—that is, buying assets that have become cheap and selling assets that have become expensive. In fact, many investors do the exact opposite!

Why is it so hard for investors to rebalance? The answer is less about “behavioral mistakes” and more about the fact that “rational” individuals care more about other things than simply maximizing investment returns. Perfectly rational individuals exhibit changing risk aversion that makes it hard for them to rebalance into high return assets, which have suffered steep recent price declines. The unwillingness to buy low and sell high is not characteristic of just retail investors, who are unaware of the finance literature and market history. Very sophisticated institutional investors, advised by investment consultants and academics, are prone to the very same behavior.1

This issue of Fundamentals reviews the empirical evidence for return improvement from rebalancing, as well as the reasons why most sensible investors don’t do it.

Why Rebalance?

A significant body of financial research has shown that asset classes exhibit long-horizon price mean-reversion.2 When an asset class falls in price, resulting in a more attractive valuation level relative to history, it is more likely to experience high subsequent returns. For example, when the S&P 500 Index falls in price, its dividend yield increases; empirically the subsequent five-year return on the S&P 500 tends to be significantly above average.3 Similarly, when corporate bond prices fall as credit spreads blow out, the forward return on corporate bonds increases.4 Price mean-reversion in asset returns suggests that a disciplined rebalancing approach in asset allocation that responds to changing valuation levels would improve portfolio returns in the long-run.5

So, if “buy low and sell high” works so well, why don’t investors rebalance? Research suggests that our risk attitude interacts in a predictable way with our wealth level and thereby influences our decision-making with respect to rebalancing. Specifically, investors tend to become more risk averse and, therefore, unwilling to add risk to their portfolios despite lower prices when their portfolio wealth declines. Investors tend to become more risk seeking and, therefore, more willing to speculate even at high prices when their portfolio wealth increases.6

The following illustration provides an intuitive way to understand this behavior. Consider a household with a certain level of income and wealth. This household anchors its standard of living (expenditure pattern) to its income/wealth profile. When positive fundamental shocks (such as a surprise jump in GDP or corporate earnings growth) hit the market, stock prices go up. A string of positive economic surprises, and the resulting equity bull market, can lead to a substantial increase in investor wealth. This market environment is also generally characterized by low unemployment, strong wage increases, healthy bonuses, and appreciation in real estate value.

The investment gain coupled with stronger income affords the household the “option” to take an extra vacation, upgrade to a larger house and/or retire earlier. The higher household income and the substantial increase in wealth also allow the household to take on more risk without affecting its standard of living and retirement prospects. The investor compartmentalizes the newfound wealth as a “windfall”—analogous to “house money” from casino winnings. Often, the investor speculates with this windfall; this is not dissimilar to the increase in aggressive betting when a gambler has just won big and is playing with “the house’s” money. The house money effect can explain why investors do not rebalance away from equities after a major rally, even though higher prices significantly reduce expected forward returns.

On the flip side, when there is a string of negative economic surprises, the resulting bear market can destroy substantial household wealth. Bear markets often coincide with high unemployment, weak wages, no bonuses, and stagnant to declining home values. The decline in income and loss of wealth pose appreciable threats to the household’s standard of living. Indeed, any further loss in portfolio value could cause a permanent and very unpleasant adjustment to the household’s quality of life and retirement planning. A severe decline might mean the investor is no longer able to afford college tuition for his children or, worse, needs to sell his house or delay retirement significantly. These events do not make for comfortable bedside conversations at an already stressful time. “Honey, I lost an additional $50,000 because I rebalanced and bought more BofA on its way down. But don’t worry, the price is likely to mean-revert higher soon.” This isn’t a good thing to say when one already has to cancel that romantic European getaway and has no prospect of a year-end bonus. Unsurprisingly, the investor becomes very risk averse to further volatility in his wealth and is unwilling to take on investment risk even in very attractively priced assets.

Similar behaviors are found among investment fiduciaries. After large market declines (which often are followed by lowered interest rates, which boost the market value of pension liabilities), pension funds are more likely to become underfunded. Any further downside volatility to the funding ratio could trigger a mandatory contribution or other adverse regulatory actions. In addition, it is also human tendency to be more blame-oriented during a time of stress, made worse by significant loss in personal wealth.7This environment does not tolerate short-term negative outcomes even when they result from a sensible investment with high long-term returns. As a result, fiduciaries also tend to be significantly more risk averse after a bear market and are generally unwilling to rebalance into risky assets after significant price declines despite the better returns.

Risk Premium Or Free Lunch?

There is strong evidence that naïve investors chase trends—for example, they over-extrapolate a recent string of good or bad news and/or follow prices in an uninformed way.8 This behavior results in irrational buying and selling, which push prices away from their rational valuations and create “alpha” opportunities for others. The truth is, supposedly sophisticated investors do not behave in a meaningfully different way; contrary to the standard claim, they are not better positioned to capture the potential “free lunch.” Time-varying risk aversion is a natural consequence of the business cycle and the associated equity market bull/bear cycle. Rational investors are too risk averse in down markets to buy stocks at attractive prices and too risk seeking in up markets to reduce their equity allocation in response to unattractive forward returns. As a result, the pattern of price mean-reversion in equities (and more broadly in all asset classes) does not become arbitraged away by “rational” investors.

Price mean-reversion in asset class returns generates what is often referred to as rebalancing return. When investors rebalance into fallen assets and away from safe assets, they also rebalance into high forward return assets and away from low forward return assets. This practice generates better portfolio performance over time than a buy-and-hold approach. Given herding and over-extrapolation by naïve investors as well as time-varying risk aversion for rational investors, the rebalancing return can be thought of as part “free lunch” and part “risk premium.” The free lunch comes from trading against behavioral mistakes of unsophisticated investors. The “risk premium” comes from bearing discomfort associated with taking on more risk when one is least able to bear risk.9

Should You Rebalance?

If the $1 million question is, “Why don’t investors rebalance?” then the $5 million question is, “Should you rebalance?” Statistically, you are likely to outperform in the long run if you rebalance in response to major price movements. However, when you buy risk assets during economic distress, there is a significant probability that, in the interim, your portfolio may suffer a greater decline than if you didn’t rebalance. In the short run, your probability of being fired as a fiduciary, of being blamed by clients you advise, and, most importantly, of marital strife, becomes moderately higher when you rebalance.

So who should rebalance? If you have over-saved significantly relative to your spending needs, rebalancing and the associated increase in short-term risk would not threaten your standard of living. For aggressive savers, rebalancing is a fantastic strategy. If you work at an organization that is truly concerned only about long-term investment performance and unconcerned by (and hold you above blame for) the short-term fluctuations, then rebalancing is a fantastic strategy for you. Other than that, one should best remember Keynes’s greatest insight (modified here for our purpose): the market can stay irrational longer than you or I can remain employed, or for that matter, happily married.10

Therefore, it isn’t so obvious that one “would” rebalance even if one were convinced of the price mean-reversion in asset returns. European equities, specifically financials, are heavily discounted—providing unprecedented yields and high expected returns. Would you rebalance with conviction into European equities? Into financials? The trepidation we experience associated with these investments doesn’t stem from our superior ability to forecast a disorderly breakup of the European Union. After all, prices are largely disciplined by Wall Street prop traders and hedge fund managers and reflect all relevant risk scenarios and probabilities. We don’t rebalance because we are first and foremost human beings with a multitude of considerations before we are investors and fiduciaries optimizing for long-term expected returns. This is perhaps why it has become fashionable for wise men to recommend “institutionalized rebalancing”—making rebalancing part of pension fund governance instead of leaving the decision to investment officers and fund trustees.11 Despite all of the intellect and adaptive learning that we bring to bear, sadly, human beings with our changing risk aversion are poorly suited as stewards for managing long-term returns.

Endnotes

  1. See Ang and Kjaer (2011) which provides case studies on pension fund and sovereign wealth fund investment behaviors.
  2. The price mean-reversion is also known as the time-series value effect. See Cochrane (1999) for a summary of the literature on long horizon mean-reversion.
  3. See Campbell and Shiller (1998) for an excellent discussion on predicting stock market returns using the dividend ratio. For a succinct treatment of the same topic, see Arnott (2003).
  4. See Bernanke (1990).
  5. See Arnott and von Germeten (1983) and Arnott and Henriksson (1989) for two of the earliest practitioner papers on rebalancing as a successful asset allocation strategy. See Brennan, Schwartz, and Lagnado (1997) for an early academic treatment on asset allocation when returns are mean-reverting and predictable. See also Campbell and Viceira (2002), Campbell, Cocco, Gomes, Maenhout, and Viceira (2001), and Xia (2002). For an excellent survey on the topic, see Campbell and Viceira (2002).
  6. See Campbell and Cochrane (1999) for a model on time-varying risk aversion driven by business cycle shocks to household standard of living.
  7. See Cohen and Janicki-Deverts (2012).
  8. See Odean (1999).
  9. See Arnott (2012).
  10. The original quote from Keynes is “the market can stay irrational, longer than you or I can stay solvent.”
  11. See Ang and Kjaer (2011) and Arnott (2012).

References

Ang, Andrew, and Knut Kjaer. 2011. “Investing for the Long Run.” In A Decade of Challenges: A Collection of Essays on Pensions and Investments, Tomas Ranzen, Editor.

Arnott, Robert D. 2003. “Dividends and the Three Dwarfs,” Financial Analysts Journal, vol. 59, no. 2 (March/April):4–6.

———. 2012. “Institutionalizing Courage,” Fundamentals (May).

Arnott, Robert D., and James N. von Germeten. 1983. “Systematic Asset Allocation,” Financial Analysts Journal, vol. 39, no. 6 (November/December):31–38.

Arnott, Robert D., and Roy D. Henriksson. 1989. “A Disciplined Approach to Global Asset Allocation,” Financial Analysts Journal, vol. 45, no. 2 (March/April):17–28.

Bernanke, Ben S. 1990. “On The Predictive Power of Interest Rates and Interest Rate Spreads,” New England Economic Review (November/December 1990):51–68.

Brennan, Michael J., Eduardo S. Schwartz, and Ronald Lagnado. 1997. “Strategic Asset Allocation,” Journal of Economic Dynamics and Control, vol. 21, no. 8–9 (June):1377–1403.

Campbell, John Y, João Cocco, Francisco Gomes, Pascal J. Maenhout, and Luis M. Viceira. 2001. “Stock Market Mean Reversion and the Optimal Equity Allocation of a Long-Lived Investor,” European Finance Review, vol. 5, no. 3:269–292.

Campbell, John Y., and John H. Cochrane. 1999. “By Force of Habit: A Consumption-Based Explanation of Aggregate Stock Market Behavior,” Journal of Political Economy, vol. 107, no. 2 (April):205–251.

Campbell, John Y., and Robert J. Shiller. 1998. “Valuation Ratios and the Long-Run Stock Market Outlook,” Journal of Portfolio Management, vol. 24, no. 2 (Winter):11–26.

Campbell, John Y., and Luis M. Viceira. 2002. Strategic Asset Allocation: Portfolio Choice for Long-Term Investors. New York, NY: Oxford University Press.

Cochrane, John H. 1999. “New Facts in Finance,” Economic Perspectives, Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago, vol. 23, no. 3:6–58.

Cohen, Sheldon, and Denise Janicki-Deverts. 2012. “Who’s Stressed? Distributions of Psychological Stress in the United States in Probability Samples from 1983, 2006, and 2009.” Journal of Applied Social Psychology, vol. 42, no. 6 (June):1320–1334.

Odean, Terrance. 1999. “Do Investors Trade Too Much?” American Economic Review, vol. 89, no. 5 (December):1279–1298.

Xia, Y. (2001). “Learning About Predictability: The Effects of Parameter Uncertainty on Dynamic Asset Allocation,” Journal of Finance, vol. 56, no. 1 (February):205–246.

 


©2012 Research Affiliates, LLC. The material contained in this document is for general information purposes only. This material is not intended as an offer or a solicitation for the purchase and/or sale of any security or financial instrument, nor is it advice or a recommendation to enter into any transaction. Nothing contained in this material is intended to constitute legal, tax, securities, financial or investment advice, nor an opinion regarding the appropriateness of any investment. Research Affiliates, LLC, is an investment adviser registered under the Investment Advisers Act of 1940 with the U.S. Securities and Exchange Commission (SEC).

JASON HSU, Chief Investment Officer, Research Affiliates, LLC

Total
0
Shares
Previous Article

Currencies: from Nullifying to Negative

Next Article

Guest Post: Major Sell Signal Triggered

Related Posts
Subscribe to AdvisorAnalyst.com notifications
Watch. Listen. Read. Raise your average.