Bonds Have More Fun (Rosenberg)

The pledge to ramp up the Treasury buying program at rough estimates of $200 billion annually could just be the thin edge of the wedge because all the Fed did was to adjust lower its near-term economic view — it still is calling for 3.5-4.2% real GDP growth for 2011, as of June. Remember when the Fed was calling for 2008 real growth of 1.8-2.5% back in October 2007 even though it was becoming so apparent at the time that the credit system was imploding (though the equity market was making a last gasp to a new high at that time) and what did we end up with? Try -2.8% for 2008. As a result, the Fed got aggressive and the funds rate went from 4.5% that month to near-zero just over a year later.

But the Fed cannot cut the funds rate any more. So it comes down to the experimental tool kit. As a result, we have to continue to read and re-read what Dr. Bernanke said he would do in these circumstances — pushing on a string with deflation risks staring us in the face — in that famous speech he gave on November 21, 2002 when he was still a Fed Governor (Deflation: Making Sure “It” Doesn't Happen Here). He laid out the guidepost for investors on how to navigate through this, and the bull flattener in bonds is the obvious strategy. One of his recommendations, as you will see in the excerpts below, involves an explicit ceiling on long bond yields at 2½%!

“Sustained deflation can be highly destructive to a modern economy and should be strongly resisted. Fortunately, for the foreseeable future, the chances of a serious deflation in the United States appear remote indeed, in large part because of our economy's underlying strengths but also because of the determination of the Federal Reserve and other U.S. policymakers to act preemptively against deflationary pressures. Moreover, as I have discussed today, a variety of policy responses are available should deflation appear to be taking hold. Because some of these alternative policy tools are relatively less familiar, they may raise practical problems of implementation and of calibration of their likely economic effects. For this reason, as I have emphasized, prevention of deflation is preferable to cure. Nevertheless, I hope to have persuaded you that the Federal Reserve and other economic policymakers would be far from helpless in the face of deflation, even should the federal funds rate hit its zero bound.

So what then might the Fed do if its target interest rate, the overnight federal funds rate, fell to zero? One relatively straightforward extension of current procedures would be to try to stimulate spending by lowering rates further out along the Treasury term structure–that is, rates on government bonds of longer maturities. There are at least two ways of bringing down longer-term rates, which are complementary and could be employed separately or in combination. One approach, similar to an action taken in the past couple of years by the Bank of Japan, would be for the Fed to commit to holding the overnight rate at zero for some specified period. Because long-term interest rates represent averages of current and expected future short-term rates, plus a term premium, a commitment to keep short-term rates at zero for some time–if it were credible–would induce a decline in longer-term rates. A more direct method, which I personally prefer, would be for the Fed to begin announcing explicit ceilings for yields on longer-maturity Treasury debt (say, bonds maturing within the next two years). The Fed could enforce these interest-rate ceilings by committing to make unlimited purchases of securities up to two years from maturity at prices consistent with the targeted yields. If this program were successful, not only would yields on medium-term Treasury securities fall, but (because of links operating through expectations of future interest rates) yields on longer-term public and private debt (such as mortgages) would likely fall as well.

Lower rates over the maturity spectrum of public and private securities should strengthen aggregate demand in the usual ways and thus help to end deflation. Of course, if operating in relatively short-dated Treasury debt proved insufficient, the Fed could also attempt to cap yields of Treasury securities at still longer maturities, say three to six years. Yet another option would be for the Fed to use its existing authority to operate in the markets for agency debt (for example, mortgage-backed securities issued by Ginnie Mae, the Government National Mortgage Association).

Historical experience tends to support the proposition that a sufficiently determined Fed can peg or cap Treasury bond prices and yields at other than the shortest maturities. The most striking episode of bond-price pegging occurred during the years before the Federal Reserve-Treasury Accord of 1951. Prior to that agreement, which freed the Fed from its responsibility to fix yields on government debt, the Fed maintained a ceiling of 2-1/2 percent on long-term Treasury bonds for nearly a decade. Moreover, it simultaneously established a ceiling on the twelve-month Treasury certificate of between 7/8 percent to 1-1/4 percent and, during the first half of that period, a rate of 3/8 percent on the 90-day Treasury bill. The Fed was able to achieve these low interest rates despite a level of outstanding government debt (relative to GDP) significantly greater than we have today, as well as inflation rates substantially more variable. At times, in order to enforce these low rates, the Fed had actually to purchase the bulk of outstanding 90-day bills. Interestingly, though, the Fed enforced the 2-1/2 percent ceiling on long-term bond yields for nearly a decade without ever holding a substantial share of long-maturity bonds outstanding. For example, the Fed held 7.0 percent of outstanding Treasury securities in 1945 and 9.2 percent in 1951 (the year of the Accord), almost entirely in the form of 90-day bills. For comparison, in 2001 the Fed held 9.7 percent of the stock of outstanding Treasury debt.”

Total
0
Shares
Previous Article

Dow Member Overbought/Oversold Levels (Bespoke)

Next Article

A Fragile Economic Outlook Continues (Hussman)

Related Posts

Get Aa's Actionable Analysis

The Morning Meeting – 7:15AM Daily.
Subscribe to AdvisorAnalyst.com notifications
Watch. Listen. Read. Raise your average.